Previous Page  40 / 73 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 40 / 73 Next Page
Page Background

THE

GRAIN AND OILSEED INDUSTRY

OF SOUTH AFRICA – A JOURNEY THROUGH TIME

ႆႂ

4 000

3 000

2 000

1 000

0

Tons (thousand)

1998/1999

1999/2000

2000/2001

2001/2002

2002/2003

2003/2004

2004/2005

2005/2006

2006/2007

2007/2008

2008/2009

2009/2010

2010/2011

2011/2012

2012/2013

2013/2014

2014/2015

Human consumption

Total output

Graph 16: Human wheat consumption versus total output

back as 1912 in an attempt to pool resources, obtain equipment and use it collectively

and promote sales.

In 1920 the Swartland producers also established a milling company, Bokomo, to

mill the members’ wheat and give them a degree of control over the products and

the price of the wheat after it had left the farm.

At the end of 1930 the producers who were involved with Wesgraan and Bokomo

started a central marketing co-operative, Sasko, which would attempt to sell wheat

throughout South Africa, stabilise its price and consolidate production. Unfortu-

nately, because of fluctuating import prices and unpredictable local production

volumes, Sasko was unable to really stabilise the price of wheat.

Wheat producers continued to exert pressure for more government support,

particularly in the light of the severe drought and declining prices of the early

1930s. This eventually led to the establishment of the Wheat Board and the

control mechanisms for the wheat industry, described in Chapter 2.

Regulation

The legislation promulgated in 1930 and 1931 to restrict the import of wheat and

wheat meal contributed to encouraging local wheat cultivation. From 1920 until the

first part of the 1930s wheat production more than doubled from 200 000 tons to

373 996 tons in 1931/1932 and 446 580 tons in 1934/1935.

At the beginning of the 1930s the relatively general view was that the wheat-to-

bread chain was ineffective and wasteful because of poor co-ordination and dam-

aging competition, and that the unstable prices were the result of speculation

by traders in the unregulated market environment. The view was that the Wheat

Board would be able to solve the problem by rationalising the chain and applying

effective price control. The desperate and virtually critical financial position of a

major part of the country’s population at that stage and the accompanying overall

concern about national wealth played a significant role in the sentiment in favour

of government control.

Although control over the import of wheat and high protective import tariffs played

a role in maintaining the domestic wheat price at a reasonable level, the prices at

the beginning of each delivery season were under severe downwards pressure be-

cause of the oversupply on the market. Co-operatives tried to regulate the supply

to the market and transfer surplus stock to subsequent marketing years. However,

the cost and risk associated with this policy was borne only by producers who

were members of the co-operatives and not by all the wheat producers. It was

therefore not a sustainable plan.

The Wheat Industry Control Board (the Wheat Board) that was established in 1935

was authorised to pay storage compensation to co-operatives and producers who

stored wheat. This made it possible for the Wheat Board to control the flow of

wheat to the market.